Contents |
Authors:
Roland Bardy, ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0002-5061-0232 PhD, BardyConsult, Mannheim, Germany Arthur Rubens, ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0002-9695-3046 PhD, Professor of Emeritus of Management, Florida Gulf Coast University, USA
Pages: 23-34
Language: English
DOI: https://doi.org/10.21272/bel.6(3).23-34.2022
Received: 12.06.2022
Accepted: 20.08.2022
Published: 30.09.2022
Download: |
Views: |
Downloads: |
|
|
|
Abstract
Natural and man-made crises and disasters often cause untold destruction, but also provide multiple opportunities for economic redevelopment post the crisis. Like other crises the COVID-19 pandemic has spurred public and private entities to become engaged in significant redevelopment efforts. Policymakers in some countries view these efforts as an opening for not only including other issues such as deficits in infrastructure and the social systems, but also for redefining their political priorities towards a “green economy”. While pursuing various policy objectives at the same time is a prudent undertaking, it seems rather questionable that politicians, under the pressure of ecological activism, would evaluate all crisis policy measures by their effect on environmental outcomes. We are seeing this in the European Union (EU) as it is about to couple its Recovery and Resilience Facility (financed through the “Next Generation EU Recovery Fund”) with its Green Deal. In the U.S., so far, the Build Back Better package and the American Rescue Plan seem to seek separate evaluation schemes for their different policy fields. The aim of this paper is to evaluate the wide-ranging opinions that exist on the intention to make recovery support contingent on ecological effects: For example, there is the classic Tinbergen Rule which states that for each policy target there must be at least one policy tool; thus, if there are fewer tools than targets, then some policy goals will not ultimately be achieved. Likewise, long-term climate change mitigation can only be achieved with long-term policies that consider and weigh out all externalities. Moreover, embarking on long term recovery plans cannot solely be formulated and implemented on ex-ante definitions of ecological impacts. The paper raises the question whether requesting ecological effects from all recovery programs is just and fair. It contrasts the various options of coupling recovery efforts and climate mitigation with state-of-the-art approaches of valuating multiple externalities: weighing the diverse externalities of policy projects can determine which policy tools to choose. It also demonstrates the downside of a policy that are solely focuses on granting financial support, if not, a project can effectively meet a pre-specified ecological and energy goal as set up by the EU and which ranks recovery projects according to their arbitrary effect on climate change. A wider scope of decision criteria will produce more effective ways to “build back better”.
Keywords: externalities, Post COVID-19, recovery programs, Tinbergen rule.
JEL Classification: D62, I15, I18.
Cite as: Bardy, R., & Rubens, A. (2022). Weighing Externalities of Economic Recovery Projects: An Alternative to Green Taxonomies that is Fairer and more Realistic. Business Ethics and Leadership, 6(3), 23-34. https://doi.org/10.21272/bel.6(3).23-34.2022
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License
References
- Battiston, S., Mandel, A., Monasterolo, I., Schütze, F., Visentin, G. (2017). A climate stresstest of the financial system. Nature Climate Change, 7(4), 283-288. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Braathen, N.A. (2007). Instrument mixes for environmental policy: how many stones should be used to kill a bird? International Review of Environmental and Resource Economics, 1(2), 185-235. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Busch, D., Ferrarini, G., and van den Hurk, A. (2021). The European Commission’s Sustainable Finance Action Plan and Other International Initiatives. Busch D., Ferrarini G., Grünewald S. (eds.), Sustainable Finance in Europe. EBI Studies in Banking and Capital Markets Law. Cham, Germany: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 19-59. [Google Scholar]
- De la Peña, R. (2021). Should monetary policy lean against the wind in a small-open economy? Revisiting the Tinbergen rule. Latin American Journal of Central Banking, 2(1), 100026. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dikau, S. and Volz, U. (2021). Central bank mandates, sustainability objectives and the promotion of green finance. Ecological Economics, 184, 107022. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- EBF and UNEP (2021). Testing the Application of the EU Taxonomy to Core Banking Products. Available at: [Link]
- EU Technical Expert Group on Sustainable Finance (2019). Spotlight on taxonomy. Available at: [Link]
- Hussain, I. and Westin, L. (1997). Tinbergen Revisited: Benefits from Infrastructure Investments in an Open Economy. Umeå Economic Studies No. 431. Umeå, Sweden: Umeå Universitet. [Google Scholar]
- Knudson, W.A. (2009). The environment, energy and the Tinbergen rule. Bulletin of Science, Technology & Society, 29(4), 308-312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kockerols, T. and Kok, C. (2019).Leaning against the wind: macroprudential policy and the financial cycle.European Central Bank Working Paper # 2223. Frankfurt: European Central Bank. [Google Scholar]
- Medina, J. and Roldós, J. (2018). Monetary and macroprudential policies to manage capital flows. International Journal of Central Banking, January issue, 201-258. Available at: [Link]
- Nersisyan, Y. and Wray, L.R. (2021). Can Biden Build Back Better? Yes, If He Abandons Fiscal “Pay Fors”. Levy Economics Institute Public Policy Brief No. 155. Annandale-On-Hudson, NY: Bard College. Available at: [Link]
- NGFS (Network for Greening the Financial System; 2019). A Call for Action – Climate Change as a Source of Financial Risk. Paris: NGFS. Available at: [Link]
- Petersen, T. (2020). Fünf Thesen zu den zukünftigen Herausforderungen für die Wirtschaftspolitik [Five theses on the future challenges for economic policy]. List Forum, 46(2), 259-268. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pigou, A.C. (1946). Income. An Introduction to Economics. London: MacMillan. 120 p. [Google Scholar]
- Schader, C., Lampkin, N., Muller, A., Stolze, M. (2014). The role of multi-target policy instruments in agri-environmental policy mixes. Journal of Environmental Management, 145, 180-190. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Scheller, H. and Körner, A.S. (2022). Federal Challenges in the Implementation of the EU’s Recovery and Resilience Facility in Germany. Gestión y Análisis de Políticas Públicas, 29, 23-37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sikora, A. (2021). European Green Deal − legal and financial challenges of the climate change. ERA Forum, Journal of the Academy of European Law, 21(4), 681-697. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Stripple, J. and Bulkeley, H., eds. (2013). Governing the climate: new approaches to rationality, power, and politics. New York: Cambridge University Press. 304 p. [Google Scholar]
- Tinbergen, J. (1956). Economic Policy: Principles and Design. Amsterdam: North Holland. 288 p. [Google Scholar]
- Tinbergen, J. (1957). The appraisal of road construction: two calculation schemes. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 39(3), 241-249. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhou, Y. and Shen, L. (2022). Confirmation bias and the persistence of misinformation on climate change. Communication Research, 49(4), 500-523. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
|